"We will pay close attention to the path of the domestic economy, which has proven more robust over 2003 than we expected. We will also be closely monitoring the path of the New Zealand dollar, with a particular focus on what it means for the export sector and the medium-term path of inflation."
That high New Zealand dollar (around similar levels to now in TWI terms) allowed the Reserve Bank to keep interest rates lower than would otherwise have been the case. Some people argue it tempted the Reserve Bank into leaving interest rates lower than they should have been for longer than they should have been. They say it contributed to the boom in house prices New Zealand saw from 2003 to 2007 and the associated build-up in foreign debt, both of which transformed our economic landscape.
The accusation is the Reserve Bank was asleep at the wheel when the signs of a boom in the housing market were evident with surging mortgage applications and fast-rising house prices in Auckland. Sound familiar?
This inaction in late 2003 eventually led to the Reserve Bank having to hike the OCR to 8.25 per cent by mid 2007 in a desperate attempt to try to slow down the housing market and get inflation under control. It had tried to let the high New Zealand dollar do the hard work of keeping inflation under control and failed. All it did was sacrifice the export sector to help borrowers and consumers carry on the housing boom for that little bit longer.
The Catch 22
This episode in New Zealand's monetary policy history showed the problems with our pure inflation targeting regime run in conjunction with a free-floating currency and no capital controls. It created a Catch 22 situation. High interest rates make the New Zealand dollar attractive, which sucks in foreign capital and pushes up economic activity and the currency even more. This in turn keeps imported inflation low and keeps the export sector from booming and creating inflation.
Essentially this encourages the growth of prices and activity in the non-tradable sector (government, financial services, real estate, construction, telecommunications) at the expense of growth in the tradable sector (exporting, manufacturing, import competition).
Here we are again in early 2012 with the Reserve Bank Governor speaking out about the high New Zealand dollar
This policy led to the following massive shift in our economy.
Our tradeable sector atrophied at the expense of the non-tradable sector . It's no surprise by the way, I think, that the lines start diverging in early 2004, shortly after the Reserve Bank governor's first murmurings about the high currency.
Nothing much has changed in New Zealand's policy settings to turn this around. The tax changes for property investors have done little to quench the demand for housing of those who are now doubly scared of investing in stocks and finance companies. Low term deposit rates leave older investors with few options but rental property. The income tax cuts for those on the highest tax bracket have actually fuelled extra property buying in Auckland, leveraged up with extra foreign debt.
Here we go again
So here we are again with a painfully high exchange rate that the Reserve Bank (or government) seems unwilling or unable to do anything about. In fact, the government's heavy offshore borrowing over the last three years has helped boost the exchange rate, as has an inflow of foreign capital looking to buy other assets such as land (which the government would like to approve the sale of).
And here we are again with a Reserve Bank Governor trying to jawbone it lower. He even threatened today to cut the Official Cash Rate if the currency rose any more because it would further ease inflationary pressures.
Meanwhile, there are signs brewing again that the same old house price inflation and non-tradable sector inflation is kicking in. Local body rates have risen twice as fast as inflation rates over the last decade and my own Auckland rates are likely to rise at least 10 per cent next year. Education cost inflation is rampant and construction cost inflation is expected to surge, albeit due partly to the earthquake rebuild.
There were $3.251 billion worth of mortgages approved in the three weeks to March 2 and $3.206 billion approved in the three weeks to December 16. The last time we saw that same sequence of heavy late summer, early autumn house lending was in December 2007 and March 2008 just as the housing boom was peaking.
Earlier this week Barfoot and Thompson reported Auckland house sales volumes growing at more than 20 per cent a year and prices rose 23 per cent in February from a year ago in the leading indicator area of the Eastern Suburbs. The BNZ-REINZ survey of estate agents out yesterday also picks up on the increasingly bubbly sounds emanating from Auckland. This survey points to the Auckland surge leading 'the next upswing in the housing market.'
Is the Reserve Bank watching?
If it is watching, it doesn't seem that worried.
Instead, the Reserve Bank focuses on the tame overall growth in housing credit, which is due largely to homeowners who are staying put repaying their mortgages early. It disguises the low-equity lending growth happening at the fringes.
Analysis by Gareth Vaughan at interest.co.nz shows a $2.9 billion rise in residential mortgages held by the big five banks with LVRs above 90 per cent to $14.2 billion in the year to September 30 last year. Aside from ASB, the biggest growth came from BNZ and Westpac. ASB's 80 per cent plus lending grew $667m in the December quarter alone to 19.5 per cent of its book.
Westpac, ASB and BNZ are all aggressively lending at 95 per cent again, so much so that ANZ's CEO warned of the potential problems of such lending here.
The Reserve Bank is convinced New Zealanders have changed their ways and are off the real estate-equity fuelled spending bandwagon.
However, even the bank is noticing something is stirring in consumer-land that it can't quite put its finger on here in the MPS:
"Yet there are some recent signs that households may have reduced their rate of saving, albeit temporarily. Retail sales growth was strong over the second half of 2011, partly a result of RWC spending. However, the level of expenditure using domestic electronic cards, and strong spending on durables, suggest some near-term strength in consumption.
It may be that this current relative strength in consumption reflects recent appreciation in the New Zealand dollar and consequent price reductions by retailers. In which case, any further rebalancing of the economy may be delayed by the current high exchange rate."
So there we have it. Yet again the strength in the currency is blocking the rebalancing we need to have.
But yet again all we get is talk
Here's the key jawboning section in the Monetary Policy Statement:
The March projection assumes the New Zealand dollar TWI depreciates modestly over the next few years. Should this not occur, all else equal, the Bank would see less need to increase the OCR through this time. While helping contain inflation, the high value of the New Zealand dollar is detrimental to the tradable sector, undermines GDP growth, and inhibits rebalancing in the New Zealand economy.
You bet it's detrimental.
So do something about it.
Instead, yet again, the Reserve Bank is bluffing because it is locked into its straightjacket of a CPI-index inflation targeting regime with a free floating currency and no capital controls. If it cuts the OCR to punish the currency traders it risks repeating the mistakes of 2003 and 2004 when it allowed the housing market to get away on everyone.
The bank could, however, intervene to push the currency down. Bollard has done it before, but has been very, very reluctant to do it again.
That would be a much better option than yet more pointless jawboning.
However, there are other more structural options that would reduce the size of this 'Catch 22' problem of capital flows pushing up the currency and inflation targeting killing off the export sector.
Other options
The Reserve Bank could target non-tradable inflation. It's heartening to see the central government finally talking with some aggression about trying to control local government inflation, although the first attempt to do it through the creation of a Super City in Auckland seems to have failed miserably. My rates may rise 18 per cent next year.
The Reserve Bank could also use some macro-prudential controls to limit the sort of low equity borrowing and foreign funded lending going into the housing market. It could impose loan to value ratio limits on housing lending. It could increase capital requirements for housing lending.
The bank's existing core funding ratio is helping to reduce the amount of hot money flowing into our housing market, but a higher ratio and a focus on domestic rather than foreign funding would help.
By the way, these sorts of macro-prudential policies are ones sanctioned by the IMF (of all people) for those economies that struggle with capital inflows distorting the structure of their economies.
What will it take for New Zealand to try to break this Catch 22?
INTEREST.CO.NZ