So if a society bases its decisions of who gets which job on race and gender, it's going to be sacrificing efficiency. If women aren't allowed to be doctors, the talent pool for doctors will be diluted, and wages will be pushed up too high, choking off output. This would be true even in a bizarro world where every man was a better doctor than every woman!
Of course that's not even remotely true, but the point is, the theory of comparative advantage doesn't care about average differences in absolute ability. If you're making rules about which type of people are allowed to do which type of job, you're hurting the economy.
Just how big of a difference does this make? A team of top economists has recently studied the question, and their results are pretty startling. In The Allocation of Talent and Economic Growth, economists Chang-Tai Hsieh and Erik Hurst of the University of Chicago Booth Business School and Charles Jones and Peter Klenow of Stanford estimate that one fifth of total growth in US output per worker between 1960 and 2008 was due to a decline in discrimination. From their abstract:
"In 1960, 94 per cent of doctors and lawyers were white men. By 2008, the fraction was just 62 per cent. Similar changes in other highly-skilled occupations have occurred throughout the US economy during the last fifty years. Given that innate talent for these professions is unlikely to differ across groups, the occupational distribution in 1960 suggests that a substantial pool of innately talented black men, black women, and white women were not pursuing their comparative advantage."
The authors' approach is clever. They treat discrimination as a tax. If you think about it, this makes sense - just as taxes discourage business activity, discrimination in employment or education discourages its victims from taking certain jobs or getting training for certain skills.
The authors explicitly allow for the possibility that different groups might have different average ability levels with respect to different occupations. They also count home production - child care and housework - as a real contribution to gross domestic product. They put these assumptions into a Roy model, which is a very flexible general equilibrium model that economists typically use when evaluating people's occupational choices.
In 1960, as you might expect, occupations were very segregated by race and gender. In 2008, they were far, far less segregated. Plugging these numbers into their model, the authors find that about 15 to 20 per cent of the growth in output per worker since 1960 can be attributed to this reduced sorting.
Since the percentage of Americans with jobs grew substantially between 1960 and 2008, this means that more than a fifth of US economic growth during that period can be attributed to reduced sorting by race and gender. The model also predicts falling wage gaps between different races and genders, which is exactly what we have seen in real life.
Reducing discrimination made us a much richer nation.
In other words, reducing discrimination made us a much richer nation.
The authors' model also allowed them to estimate just how far discrimination has fallen, by examining the changes in the labour market and working backward. The authors also estimate what would happen if discrimination were to fall all the way to zero. Output per worker, according to the model, would rise a further 10 per cent to 15 per cent!
The implications of this result couldn't be clearer. Eliminating race and gender discrimination continues to be an economic priority for the US.
One way to do that is to promote more economic competition. The late Nobel-winning economist Gary Becker showed that competition can exert powerful pressure on companies to hire and promote workers based on efficiency instead of on race and gender. We probably did a lot of that unwittingly in the late 1970s and early 1980s, with deregulation and free trade. But competition will always be imperfect, and we need other tools as well.
Simply reducing individual prejudice would be a wonderful way of attacking discrimination at the source. That's why the continuing social movements for greater racial and gender equality are valuable - not just for reasons of fairness but for our economic future.
Noah Smith is an assistant professor of finance at Stony Brook University and a freelance writer for finance and business publications.
- Bloomberg