In fact about half of our manufactured imports come from low-wage countries, which is an increase from less than 10 per cent, 40 years ago. This is important when we consider that 80 per cent of the value of Australia's imports comes from manufactured goods.
When we import cheap products we are effectively importing cheap labour. This effective boost to the supply of cheap labour drives down import prices and wages in Australasia. A similar effect happens when businesses outsource products or services to another country.
Again this is a global phenomenon affecting all industrialised countries including the US and Australia. The most common primary motivation for global outsourcing cited by companies is cost cutting. Business functions that are typically outsourced are manufacturing procurement and services such as information technology, legal, facilities management, finance and human resources.
International competition can also reduce wages through migration of labour to Australia, although here the empirical evidence is less clear. The effect of migration on wages depends whether it creates enough jobs to absorb the extra workers, but teasing this out is not straightforward.
Net overseas migration has increased as a share of the population from 47 per cent in 2000 to 54 per cent in 2015. And the skilled migrant share of permanent migrants has increased from 55 per cent in 2000 to 68 per cent in 2015.
Not only are migrants increasing as a share of the population, but a higher share of them are skilled.
And their labour participation rates are high. In November 2016 the labour force participation rate for recent migrants and temporary residents combined was at 70 per cent, which is higher than the overall participation rate for Australia of 66 per cent. The effect is to boost the overall labour participation rate.
Globalisation has increased international competition through imports of both goods and labour.
Importantly, recent migrants have higher skill levels than others in the labour force. Unless sufficient extra jobs are created to absorb these extra workers, wages could go down, and more so in skilled wages relative to unskilled wages.
However this effect on job creation is hard to pin down and so research shows the effect on wages could go either way.
One US study argues that the additional jobs created are not enough to absorb the extra workforce, creating slack in the labour market and a drop in wages. However, another study using Australian data shows an increase in wages with increased immigrant worker numbers but it's small and statistically insignificant. Another Australian study found no net impact at all.
The question turns mainly on the net effect of migration on the quantity and quality of nation's investment in things like buildings, equipment and the like that are used by businesses. If this is sufficiently strong, then the workforce will be more productive and wages will tend to rise, otherwise they will fall.
So while it's easy to calculate the extra workers from migration, it is much harder to calculate the effect they will have on investment and therefore on wages.
Globalisation has increased international competition through imports of both goods and labour. Imports of goods have tend to depress wage growth. The effect of labour imports through migration on wage growth depends on whether the boost to the workforce dominates any boost to job creation and that's unclear in theory and evidence.
This article was originally published on The Conversation. Read the original article.
Ross Guest, Professor of Economics and National Senior Teaching Fellow, Griffith University